Categorie archief: Sociologie

Sociologie, Overleving oermaarschappij

(1) George Thomson, “Studies in Ancient Greek Society – The Prehistoric Aegean”, Citadell Press 1965; “… the ancient oikos was an integral unit in the social life of the period. The city-state was a community of oikoi. The family estate was owned by right of descent from one of the cofounders of the city and carries with it the right of citizenship. In commercialised cities like Athens these ancient tenures had for the most part disappeared, but a Sparta the original estates were never forgotten and they must have been remembered in many of the colonies overseas. Even at Athens, when citizenship was granted to a foreigner, it was the practice to enrol him in a particular tribe, phratry, and deme and sometimes to endow him with a house and land. Only in that way did he become a full member of the community in the Athenian law-courts we hear of a person laying claim to an estate on the plea of kinship to the deceased owner but never of disputes about land turning on evidence of sales or purchase: ‘The line of argument always leads to the proof of near kinship, by blood or adoption, the previous owner, and their gift of inheritance seems taken for granted as following incontrovertibly the establishment of the required relationship.’ // Of course this does not mean that estates were never bought or sold, but that even at Athens, under a monetary economy, deeds of transfer were not formally recognised as overriding the claims of kinship. In other cities the alienation of the original estates was actually illegal. //

(2) Passim: The city-state had thus arisen as a union of joint families, each of which possessed in perpetuity a holding of land inherited from one of the founders. The holding had been created at the same time as the family. It may have been subsequently divided, but then so was the family that owned it. The family was bound to the soil on which it lived. That begin so, it is incumbent on us to determine so far as we can the manner in which the holdings were distributed. / We have already made some progress in this direction. It has been she shown that the attic demes began as clan settlements of the same type as the Anglo-Saxon ‘ings’ and hams’; and that the rule of succession to the oikos corresponds to the Anglo-Saxon law of gavelkind. We must also, of course remember that the old English land system was by no means peculiar to this country. It occurs in analogous forms in all parts of Europe, India, China, Central and South America. It is in fact characteristic of the primitive village community, ‘At Athens under the democracy it was a regular policy to relive unemployment and at the same time to secure strategically points by settling poor citizens overseas on conquered territory. The land selected was divided equally into as many holdings as there were citizens enlisted under the scheme and the holdings were then distributed by lot. The settlers required to reside within the territory, but as a rule they did not work the land themselves. That was done by the native proprietors, who were left in occupation subject to the payment of an annual rent.”

Krijgsgevangenschap

(1) Yvon Garlan, “Ancient culture and society  – War in the ancient world: a social history”, Chatto & Windus 1976; “The priceof ransom varied accoring to th esocial condition of those involved, the political situation in general, and the state of th slave market. / Teh very fact thet tye wer captives usually made it imporsible for prisoners to pay for their liberty. Someone else therfore had to assure the responsibility, in archaic societies ofthen the kinsmen. A law of Gortyn in Crete of about 460 B imosed an obligation on Gortynians to buy back members of thier hetairia who were put up for sale by the enemy. Later the sate itself, withthat heigtened sense of colective solidarity which inspried it in early times, sometimes intervened directly [as in Rome, durig the second Punic war]. Alternativley, a semi-public organ for mutua aid, like the chruch in the ate Emprie, performed this function. Between allied or freindly peoples the subject was, on occasion incorporated in a treat. For instance, in about 260 BC such a treaty was dwan up bttween Miletus and the Cretan cities of Cnossus, Gortyn and Phaestus. And at all times, men urned to those who felt a ocation, more or less alruistic, for the role of benefactor [euergetes]. Increasingly however, withthe decline of family solidarity, of mutual help between citizens and of the spirit of ‘euergetism’, it bacme necesar to depend up the nonbenevolent intervention of individuals /

(2) Passim: In theory, a man whose rights and personakity had been in suspension while he was in captivityshould have automatically recoverd his old status th moment he set foot onhis ative sild. The Romans spoke of teh right of postliminuim which restored to the ‘living dead’ his former condition, his possessions andhis family. [not until the time of Constantine as a woman who hwas unable to prove thedeath of her husband in captivity prohibited from remarying.] But in fact thngs did not always work out this way, either because the repratrated man had frist to prove he had en honourable captured, and then retuned to his country, or, as was more ofthen the case, bceause he had First to repay the ransom advanced in his name by an intermediary. In such cases the ancients took considerably parins to safeguard the interersts of both parties. Bt in Greece an in the Roman Empirere form th end of th second century to the Froman Empierse fom th end of th second century to the foruth a ‘man brought back from teh enemy’ belonged to his ’benefacotor’ as a slave,until the ransom was epaid. The Gortyn code expressly stipulated that a free man ransomed from a foreigner ‘will be at th disposal of th man who bought him the extinction of this obligaion was sanctioned by a form of manmission. This type of slave was, however, of a very particular kind: he engaged his ervices without abndoning either his personaity or his patriony. Le lost his independence, not hs liberty.

(3) Pasim: At other times, under the roman Republic and at the beginning of the Emprie, it even seems that ransom was juristicaly assimilated intothe law of debt, not of sale. Thse varied measures rested on the twofold desire to respect the native liberty of a citizien onhis own territory and, in termsof the international situation, to encourage the practive ce of bying back prisonersof war. The guarantees geven to the buyer were increased or diminished accoring to the gravity of the problems which such a course presented.On the hwole, the fate of prisoners was erhaps ameloratd. But we shold be mistaken is we saw this tend as evidence of hmnitarian feelings at work or of a growing respect for human personality.Esentialy, the motivation was social or political, reflecting the interests of the community rahter than of the individueal. Hence, when it was in their interest – for example in the conquestof Gaul by Caesar- the romans easliy reverted to the most primitive ways of treating prisoners, untoubled by any scruples.”

Sociologie, Rome, Republiek

(1) Olga Tellegen-Couperus, “A short history of Roman Law”, Routledge 1993; “Roman society was made up of two elements, the familia and the gens. A familia consisted of all those persons who were in some way subject to the power of a pater familias. This power could be based  on parentage, marriage or adoption and was in principle unlimited. Religious norms imposed a certain number of constraints and the possible abuse of power by a pater familias was kept in check by strong social control. Within the familia the pater familias was the only person who had any rights in private law. Being subject to the power of a pater familias had nothing to do with age; a person was in this position until the pater familias died or relinquished his power in a formal manner, e.g. by means of emancipation the person concerned was then independent and could have his own property (sui iuris). Familiae with a common progenitor (even if he was a legendary figure) together founded a gens and had a common gens-name. They could hold meetings and pass resolutions that were binding on the members, and they had a common cult. According to Livy (Aburbe condita, 10.8.9) at first only patricians formed a gens, but names of old plebeian gentes are also mentioned in the sources. The law of the XII Tables of 449 BC contained rules on guardianship and intestate succession for the gentes; these rules were applied until the end of the republic. The gentes themselves continued to exist during the early empire, but then they no longer had any juridical function.”

Sociologie, Rome, 2e eeuw na Christus

(1) Div., “A Companion to Roman Religion”, Blackwell ?; “After the reign of Hadrian, the Panhellenion opened a new area of activity for ambitious aristocrats, since contribution to the preparation of the candidature dossier and then participation in the administration of the League was a great honor, in that all its important officials were rich Roman citizens and some of these, or some of their descendants, had had senatorial or equestrian career. The prestige inherent in serving in the League arose from the close association of the Panhellenion with the ruling power. Service in the Panhellenion might also be a means of furthering one’s career. It offered members of the local elite the opportunity of contact with a Roman institution at a time when, although the senate and the equestrian order were open to provincials, the places available in these orders were severely limited. By their actions that did such good to their cities, these personages invested in their future and strengthened the chances of ensuring a successful career for their descendants, since it was the privileged political and judicial status of local families that brought future knights and senators to the attention of the Roman authorities.”

——————

(2) Arjan Zuiderhoek, “The politics of munificence in the Roman world- Citizens, elites and benefactors in Asia Minor”, Cambridge University Press 2009;  “The old polis ideal, which defined the city essentially as a community of people, of citizens, had remained central to Greek civic ideology during the Roman imperial period. This is evident, for instance, from the way cities always described themselves, or were referred to, as a community of people – the Athenians, the Pergamenes, the Prusans – instead of a place. It also shows from the great value people attached to their civic affiliation, referring to it whenever possible, in inscriptions, papyri and so forth. It shows from the fact that Roman citizenship, which became increasingly widespread in the east during the second century ad, never managed to replace local citizenship. Instead, the two statuses simply co-existed. And it shows from the fact that cities regarded the grant of their citizenship to outsiders who had done them well as one of the highest honours they could bestow, at least on a foreigner.2 Members of the urban elites, however powerful, wealthy or influential in the wider world of the Empire, first and foremost felt themselves to be citizens of their native communities, and, most importantly, fellow citizens of their poorer compatriots. Dio Chrysostom told the assembly of his native Prusa that no praise was dearer to him than that of his fellow citizens, ‘even if the whole Greek world and the Roman people too, were to admire and praise me’. He went on to say that he would not have preferred even Athens, Argos or Sparta, ‘the first and most famous of the Greek cities’, to Prusa: For although many people in many lands have invited me both to make my home with them and to take charge of their public affairs . . . yet I never accepted such a proposal even by so much as a single word, and I did not even acquire a house or a plot of ground anywhere abroad, so that I might have nothing to suggest ahome-land anywhere but here.

(3) Passim: We should of course allow for the rhetoric, but even if we do, the sentiment still strikes sincere. Dio, we should remember, was something of a celebrity. He had travelled widely and seen many of the Empire’s great cities, including Rome, with his own eyes.He had high friends everywhere, and was even an acquaintance of the emperors Nerva and Trajan. And yet, he devoted much of his life and energies to politics and munificence in small-town Bithynian Prusa, in spite of considerable and frequently nasty opposition from jealous local rivals. It is a pattern known also from the careers of other eastern grandees. In a recent study Giovanni Salmeri provides a whole list of eastern aristocrats who, despite great wealth and wide political influence, chose to devote much of their lives to Greek municipal politics in the east, sometimes even aborting senatorial or equestrian careers for the purpose. Among them are the sophist M. Antonius Polemo, the grand Lycian benefactor Opramoas of Rhodiapolis (who was not even a Roman citizen), the historians-cum-senators Flavius Arrianus and A. Claudius Charax, the 2 Roman emperors could and did acknowledge the importance polis ideals and institutions held for their Greek-speaking subjects. For a startling recent example see the letter by the (admittedly philhellene) emperor Hadrian to the citizens of Naryka in eastern Locris published by Jones (2006). … equestrian C. Iulius Demosthenes of Oenoanda, and, famously, Herodes Atticus.4 Like Dio and (probably) the individuals just mentioned, Plutarch too extols the ideal of service to one’s native community, criticising those wealthy eastern citizens who scorned local politics out of eagerness for a career in the Roman administration.

(4) Passim: Local patriotism and love of one’s fellow citizens is also the motive most frequently encountered in inscriptions recording gifts by generous members of the urban elite. Hence when elite donors motivate their gifts by saying that they have ‘loved my dearest homeland from my earliest youth’ or wish ‘to requite the native town that bred and loves me’ we have no reason to doubt their sincerity. As always, the discourse of praise of honorific inscriptions is instructive: as Peter Brown notes, a rich benefactor was invariably praised ‘for being a philopatris, a “lover of his home-city”, never for being a philoptochos, a ‘lover of the poor.’ / As these last two examples indicate, it is euergetism which perhaps allows us to appreciate best just how central the notion of citizen community was to the civic ideology of the imperial Greek cities. As I shall demonstrate in this section, benefactors by means of their gifts to the citizen community helped to define that community in a very real sense. Through the character and structure of their public generosity, elite benefactors managed to endow their communities with a specific sense of corporate, collective identity. Their selection of what to donate and what not betrays a clear and sharply defined sense of what was needed for ‘the good life’ of the Greco-Roman citizen, and this was what they provided their fellow citizens with. Given its central ideological focus on the citizen community and the citizen ‘good life’, it is no wonder that euergetism proliferated precisely during the second century ad. As we saw in the previous chapter, it was during this period that great disparities of wealth between elite and non-elite citizens became increasingly strongly felt in urban society, as civic elites reached new and unprecedented levels of riches, while a socially and politically restive demos, some of whom perhaps saw their income rise a little as well (though not nearly as fast or on so large a scale as those of the elite), staked out a claim to a share of the new elite wealth.

(5) Passim: Also, political power had largely become the prerogative of a privileged group of very rich elite families active in the urban council, whose members acquired ever more characteristics of a true ordo, separated culturally, socially, politically and economically from the mass of ordinary citizens. These developments had the potential to erode the unifying ideal of citizen community, the very ideological notion that provided much of the basis for social and political stability in the post-Classical Greek cities. Open large-scale social conflict was perhaps rare, but contemporary commentators were acutely aware of the tension that was constantly brewing under the skin of civic life, as was Plutarch when he implored elite politicians by all means not to neglect their role as benefactors. Moreover, we frequently hear of what were sometimes violent clashes between elite and non-elite citizens in the late first and second centuries ad. These, as we saw in the previous chapter, usually took the shape of conflicts between the boule/the notables on the one hand, and the demos on the other. Given the continuous threat of social antagonism as a consequence of contemporary economic and socio-political developments, the unifying ideal of citizen community increasingly needed to be re-emphasised, and euergetism turned out to be the ideal instrument to do just that. Not only did most benefactors emphasise with their gifts the importance of the citizen community and the civic way of life, but also the very process of exchange that constituted euergetism can be said to have exemplified the ideological centrality of the citizen body. By means of a sort of unspoken, perhaps even largely unconscious, ‘pact’ elite citizens through their munificence made it in fact possible for their poorer fellow citizens to enjoy those amenities essential to the life of the trueGreco-Roman citizen.

(6) Passim: In exchange, the non-elite citizenry, despite occasional struggles, in the end accepted the rule of the rich bouleutic families and through their consent legitimated the latter’s position of power. Euergetism thus prevented the unifying notions of citizenship and citizen-community from losing their meaning completely in an age of ever-growing disparities of wealth and political power within the citizen body. By allowing poorer citizens unhindered access to all the amenities necessary for the citizen-‘good life’ – gymnasia, baths, theatres, temples, games, festivals, distributions – euergetism did not just serve to define the very notion of the Greco-Roman ‘good life’. By unceasingly honouring the entitlements implicit in citizenship, euergetism also powerfully and unequivocally underlined the fact that citizenship still constituted the primary organising principle of civic life. Consequently, For the concept of entitlement see Sen (1982) 1–8. Broadly following Sen, I think we could define entitlements as those aspects of an individual’s legal, social, political and economic position that largely because of euergetism, it still meant something to be a citizen of a polis during the high Roman Empire. In plain terms, citizenship often allowed you a larger share of the cake than you would have received had you simply been a non-citizen resident. Euergetism thus functioned as the primary distribution mechanism that turned citizenship-entitlements from a theoretical possibility into an everyday reality. As such, euergetism’s palliative social effects were increasingly needed during the second century ad, when the divisions of wealth and power within the citizen body slowly reached their apex and their corroding influence on civic unity needed to be battled against on all fronts.

(7) Passim: It is no coincidence that the theme of homonoia figures so prominently in the literature and epigraphy of the east during the high Empire. Euergetism did much to make homonoia possible and to ensure its continuous existence; non-elite citizens considered it only natural that the elite did their best to allow them their rightful share of the increasingly sumptuous forms of civic life the new wealth made possible.  The balance, however, was precarious. As Plutarch realised, the elite had better live up to the facts of nature . . . We should however note that, over the course of many centuries since the Classical period, the civic ideal did not remain unchanged. The notion of the polis as a community of political equals, which had prevailed in Classical times, started to make less and less sense in the far more oligarchic Greek civic world which came into existence from the later Hellenistic period onwards. Consequently, during the Roman imperial period, when the oligarchisation and hierarchisation of urban society became increasingly visible and institutionally formalised, the civic ideal had taken on a decidedly new form. The citizen community was, as we just saw, still the central element around which civic ideology was constructed, but it was now refashioned into a far more hierarchical shape. We can see this clearly in various areas of euergetism. Public distributions almost invariably determine the extent to which he has access to the resources he needs. In the words of Sen (1982), economists often tend to argue ‘in terms of what exists rather than in terms of who can command what’ (Sen’s emphasis). A citizen of a Greek polis or the Roman Republic/Empire could, in various ways, more easily command access to (vital) resources than a non-citizen, hence in the ancient world citizenship functioned as a form of entitlement. See also Jongman (2002b) and (2006) for the benefits Roman citizenship might confer.

(8) Passim: This ‘naturalness’ was underwritten ideologically by the populace’s use of ‘family language’ while addressing or honouring generous elite members, calling them ‘fathers’ or ‘mothers’ of the city or demos: see Pleket (1998) 213–14 for evidence and literature. What is more natural for fathers or mothers than to desire to feed their children, and to provide them, as far as possible, with the essentials they need to lead a proper and fulfilling life? The notion must however also have been congenial to an oligarchic elite, since it implied a patriarchal, deferential society in which the poor ‘children’ are submissive and obey the rich ‘fathers’. See also van Rossum (1988) 152–5; Robert (1966) 85–6; Zuiderhoek (2008). Focused on citizens, and if they sometimes included non-citizen groups, these mostly received (far) less than citizens. However, within the citizenry, as we shall see, a variety of privileged groups received handouts that were sometimes considerably larger than those granted to ordinary citizens (politai).11 Festivals usually expressly involved the entire citizen body, and even glorified its unity, as citizens together worshipped their gods, honoured their traditions, commemorated their collective past and collectively enjoyed and participated in games and athletics. On closer inspection, however, there are often many hints suggesting that this same citizen body was now perceived as structured in a distinctly hierarchical way. Such a hierarchical definition of civic society made far more ideological sense in a society where power structures were so explicitly founded on a highly unequal division of wealth, power and prestige. Indeed, I would argue that it was precisely this redefinition of the citizen community in terms of a hierarchy of status groups that allowed the oligarchic urban societies of the Roman east to retain their sense of civic unity.

(9) Passim: By integrating the concept of status hierarchy into their idealised picture of the citizen community, the urban societies of the Roman east managed to devise an ideological justification for the huge social cleavages dividing their citizen bodies. The compromise was frequently an uneasy one, as our evidence for social tensions reveals, but it tended to work reasonably well provided that its central message was continuously reinforced and the elite lived up to their side of the bargain. Once more we see how crucial euergetism was to the stable functioning of urban society in the Roman east.”

—————————-

(10) Arjan Zuiderhoek, “The politics of munificence in the Roman world- Citizens, elites and benefactors in Asia Minor”, Cambridge University Press 2009;  “Although the ancient world knew rural shrines and temples, the city was in many ways a focal point of religious activity.Moreover, collective engagement in religious cults, festivals and ceremonies created strong symbolic bonds between citizens, thus reinforcing their sense of unity and corporate identity. Hence, a true polis was rich in temples, shrines, sanctuaries, altars, statues of the gods, and munificence abundantly reflects this. The preponderance of donations of religious structures which Fig. 5.2 reveals is indicative of a pronounced religious dimension of euergetism that, as will become evident below, we can also discern in many donated games and festivals. If euergetism was, as I argue, strongly bound up with ideas of civic identity and Greco-Roman ideals of urban civilisation and civic life, then the religious aspect of many forms of munificence indicates how deeply religiously embedded such ideas and ideals were. The inhabitants of the cities of the eastern Roman Empire in the second century ad still very much lived in a world full of gods. This was no pagan world in decline, as some older authors would have us believe, and euergetism decidedly shows this. Many elite benefactors had been priests at some stage in their career, and not a few actually donated in that capacity. We should note that among benefactors’ contributions, temples and sanctuaries for Roman emperors and the imperial cult figure almost as frequently as structures for other Greek, Greco-Roman or local deities. Here we touch on the almost seamless integration of the religious and the political in Greco-Roman civic life that was so strongly emphasised by Simon Price in his briljant study of the Roman imperial cult in Asia Minor.  At the local level, this integration might manifest itself in the community’s political mythology, which might relate the foundation and history of the city to important deities, or events and places important to the life of gods or demi-gods.

(11) Passim: Empire-wide, it showed in the cultivation of the religious connections between the deified Roman emperors and the faithful cities that were their subjects. The recurring ritual celebration of the community’s relations with the divine, whether in the shape of a living or deceased emperor, Olympian gods, demi-gods or local deities, strongly stimulated a sense of civic unity by symbolically placing the community as a corporate entity over and against its gods. Small wonder, therefore, that elites, interested as they were in maintaining such a sense of unity among the citizenry in the face of growing disparities of wealth and power within it, made religion such a prominent area of their munificence. As with Price’s study of the imperial cult, it is the integration of religion and politics that provides the key to the explanation.”

————————–

(12) Arjan Zuiderhoek, “The politics of munificence in the Roman world- Citizens, elites and benefactors in Asia Minor”, Cambridge University Press 2009;  “The second most popular type of structure among elite appears to have been the stoa. Here, financial calculation may have played a part. Stoas of course could be frightfully expensive, especially large and sumptuous ones. On the whole, however, it seems reasonable to think that a normal-sized stoa would have been a cheaper option, if one wished to donate an entire new building and not merely to make a contribution to an existing structure, than, say, an entire theatre or bath–gymnasium complex. Hence budgetary shrewdness might go a long way towards explaining the popularity of the stoa among civic benefactors, but financial considerations are not the whole story. The eastern stoa or colonnaded avenue, with its air of luxurious urbanity, was a highly appreciated architectural form in the cities of imperial Asia Minor, and we find it almost everywhere. As a combination of the traditional Greek stoa and the Roman via portica, it was a crucial element of what has been termed the typical ‘Asiatic urbanism’ of the cities of AsiaMinor in imperial times, a creative synthesis of Hellenistic and Roman architectural ideas that revitalised the ‘Romanized Greek polis in luxurious, nearly Baroque architectural forms’. The so-called ‘Syrian’ colonnades – the first large one was built by Herod the Great in Syrian Antioch around 20 bc – provided an essential material backdrop to civic life (much like skyscrapers have become the emblematic structures of modern American cities), as the ruins of modern Turkey still testify. They surrounded agoras and the courts of gymnasia, lined major streets and functioned as covered walks wherever they could be squeezed into the urban layout.

(13) Passim: Dio Chrysostom went to great lengths to have one constructed at Prusa, as part of his grand scheme to turn his native town into a proper city worthy of the name. Elite benefactors, eager to transform their cities into magnificent civic landscapes, found in the colonnaded avenue their perfect form. Stoas, colonnaded streets, were civic surroundings par excellence. Next are baths and gymnasia. In Roman Asia Minor, these two were usually combined in one single complex, a synthesis of the Hellenistic gymnasium and the Roman bath building. As such, like the colonnaded streets, these complexes can also be considered part of the great ‘Asiatic’ architectural renewal of the Greek cities in AsiaMinor. In Greek culture, physical exercise and athletics in the gymnasium had always constituted an essential part of what it meant to be a citizen, as had bathing and its facilities in Rome (though the Greeks had their baths too). However, the proliferation of the bath–gymnasium complexes in Roman imperial Asia Minor was strongly associated with a general ‘renaissance’ of gymnasial culture, as evidenced by the contemporaneous craze for agonistic games and festivals, to which members of the civic elite contributed significantly both as benefactors and participants. The significance of the bath–gymnasium complexes for civic life and culture was, however, not confined to providing a context for agonistic contests. In many ways (and very much like the agoras of the Greek cities at this time), through their multiplicity of functions, the bath–gymnasium complexes became focal points of civic life and citizen interaction in the public sphere, combining leisure, sport, religion (most bath–gymnasium complexes included a sanctuary for the imperial cult)27, education and sociability, all in one building. In the words of the archaeologist George Hanfmann, ‘[w]ith its multiple functions as civic center, club house, leisure area, school, and place of worship of the emperors, the gymnasium now replaced the palace and the temples as the major concern of the Asiatic cities’.

(14) Passim: Given this centrality of bath–gymnasium complexes to contemporary civic culture, we can only conclude that elite benefactors’ fondness for donating them once again betrays their focus on providing their fellow citizens with the amenities essential to a proper citizen existence. From here on the discussion becomes slightly more complicated. Figure 5.2, the graph of whole buildings, gives the category ‘miscellaneous’ next, followed by the category ‘governmental structures’. However, if we look at Fig. 5.3, which is a graph that includes all contributions to public buildings in my database, i.e. also the partial ones, a somewhat different pattern emerges. We should of course bear in mind the classificatory problems associated with partial contributions discussed above, which make the classification in Fig. 5.3 somewhat more arbitrary than that in Fig. 5.2. Note that there are a few striking differences between the two graphs. First, when we include all recorded contributions to public building, the bath–gymnasium complex emerges as a more popular target for munificence than the stoa (in Fig. 5.2, it is the other way around). Second, whereas in Fig. 5.2 governmental structures (council houses, offices for the agoranomoi and so forth) surpass theatres, in Fig. 5.3 the theatre stands out as the more popular object of benefactions. The agora too appears as a more favoured object when we include all contributions (as in Fig. 5.3), instead of just donations of whole buildings (as in Fig. 5.2). The same is true, if only just, for libraries, while stadiums make their sole appearance in Fig. 5.3. In all these cases, I think the explanation for the difference between the two graphs is similar. Bath–gymnasium complexes, theatres, agoras, libraries and stadiums were often huge and complex structures, and hence frightfully expensive. Only the richest of the richest local elite families could afford to donate such buildings in their entirety.

(15) Passim: Given the prominence of bath–gymnasium complexes among the donations of whole buildings set out in Fig. 5.2, these seem to have been the least costly of the structures just mentioned. It is also quite conceivable that as gifts they were so popular among the citizenry, and hence brought donors such enormous prestige, that people were willing virtually to ruin themselves just to be able to provide one. As for religious structures, many of these would have been rather smallish shrines, not big temples (although these are also present among recorded gifts), and hence not extremely expensive. Their prominence in the subset of whole buildings (Fig. 5.2) should therefore not surprise us. The relative cheapness of stoas (not universal: we know of very extensive and sumptuous examples too) we have already discussed. What all buildings with different locations in Figs. 5.2 and 5.3, perhaps with the exception of libraries (bath–gymnasium complexes, theatres, agoras, stadiums) have in common is that they were both expensive and essential to civic life and a proper citizen existence. I have just discussed bath–gymnasium complexes. Theatres were used for plays, shows, gladiatorial combats, wild beast hunts, all kinds of festivities, religious happenings, but also for mass meetings of the citizenry, in assembly, to honour a benefactor, or welcome a governor. Thus, theatres provided the citizenry with  crucial venues for collective entertainment, festivity, and the expression of communal feeling and popular political will. The centrality of the agora to civic life hardly needs explaining. Most agoras combined the functions of local market, place of worship, venue for social interaction and sociability, centre of competitive elite display (in the form of monuments and statues) and stage for general architectural and sculptural splendour. Hence, in a very literal sense, the agora was a centre of civic life. The stadium, again, would be crucial to certain types of public entertainment, the absence of which would be unthinkable in a truly civilised Greek urban community. As a venue for horse racing, athletics and other forms of sport and competition, with citizens as both spectators and participants, the stadium was indispensable. In fact, the comparison between Figs. 5.2 and 5.3 underscores in a crucial way the sheer importance to civic life of the structures just discussed, and hence their popularity among elite benefactors.

(16) For what the comparison primarily reveals is the absolute determination of elite benefactors to contribute to just this set of structures, despite the highly costly nature of many of the buildings in question. These were the buildings a benefactor was supposed to provide his fellow citizens with, no matter how expensive they were. If that meant that many such benefactions could only be partial contributions (embellishments, restorations, and gifts of architectural elements), then this did not trouble most donors too much. What mattered was that one was seen to be contributing to precisely those public buildings that so crucially marked out the civic character of the community, and that were so essential to the day-to-day experience of civic life. By contributing to these types of buildings, elite members would thus be able both (as individuals) to maximise prestige and (as a collective) to show that they lived up to their part of the bargain by providing their non-elite fellow citizens with precisely those architectural amenities which were indispensable to civic life.”

———————–

(17) Arjan Zuiderhoek, “The politics of munificence in the Roman world- Citizens, elites and benefactors in Asia Minor”, Cambridge University Press 2009;  “In his book on the Salutaris foundation and in a seminal paper on the festival of Demosthenes at Oenoanda, Guy Rogers has specifically, and, to a large extent, convincingly, stressed the importance of the political processes surrounding major acts of euergetism. And, though there has been some criticism, other ancient historians have tended to follow suit. In particular, Rogers has pointed out the role played by the demos in determining the outcome of proposed acts of munificence. It is specifically this element of his analysis that I want to elaborate in the context of the general thesis on euergetism developed in this study. Though the bouleutai represented the effective ruling class of the cities of the Roman east, the rest of the population was by no means completely powerless politically. To begin with, the non-elite citizenry could simply rebel. This might cause serious trouble for the elite, and they did their utmost to avoid it. And, as is one of the main themes of this study, euergetism was in fact a crucial element in their strategy of conflict-avoidance. Secondly, however, and this is vital, euergetism was fundamentally a process of exchange. Generous elite members wanted something in return for their gifts. And the things they wanted – honours, prestige, and, with an eye to their role as members of the ruling elite, social stability and the legitimation of their elite position – could only be secured from the demos, the non-elite citizenry. Up to a point, this fact afforded the demos a measure of control over the behaviour of their elite superiors, at least when it came to munificence.

(18) Passim: The people could (and sometimes did)69 simply refuse to bestow any honours on a benefactor. A politically shrewd benefactor would therefore allow some room for participation of the demos in the deliberations concerning the eventual outcome of his munificence, as Salutaris did at Ephesos, and Demosthenes at Oenoanda. Fellow elite members, however, could not be ignored either. Euergetism was a field of intense competition between elite individuals for honour and prestige, and a potential benefactor would be very unwise to bypass the boule during the planning phase of his munificence. The boule would be sure to claim a role for itself, would aim to prevent the rise of political mavericks, would attempt to make sure that one single individual did not gain too much prestige, and that some of the prestige gained would rub off on the council as a whole. Through the processes of deliberation taking place in the boule and the assembly after the benefaction had initially been proposed, other elite members and the nonelite citizenry would thus be able to influence both the nature and the shape of the eventual benefaction to their own advantage. However, the benefactors themselves also gained from the whole process. The devotion of large amounts of political time and energy to the benefactions of members of the ruling elite only served to underwrite the latter’s crucially important position at the head of the civic hierarchy. Thus context and meaning were added to their leading political role and to their generosity, by integrating both of these deeply into the social and political fabric of contemporary civic society.

(19) Passim: If this model of background negotiations and participation of boule and demos in the political processes surrounding benefactions is true for most benefactions we know of from the Roman east (as I think it is), then an important conclusion follows. This is that virtually all benefactions we know of, recorded as they were on honorific or building inscriptions, represent cases in which the euergetist system had ‘worked’. If the background negotiation model is broadly correct, it means that, in all these cases, the benefactor had got what he/she wanted in terms of prestige, legitimation and so forth. But it also means that the non-elite citizenry had been able to ensure, as far as was within its power, that the benefaction concerned would be such that they, as citizens, would gladly receive it, as befitting their status and preferences as members of a polis community. It implies that the ideas and ideologies concerning civic cohesion and civic hierarchy which we see represented in many acts of munificence, and which have been the subject of this chapter, by and large found broad acceptance among both elite benefactors and the non-elite recipients of their generosity. For, if any of the above conditions had not been fulfilled, the benefaction would never have made it through the negotiation process, and would never have reached the final stage of the honorific inscription. Ultimately, then, the thousands of honorific inscriptions for benefactors we have left from the Roman world constitute the surest indication we have for the success of the euergetist system in heading off social and political conflict. Precisely because they survive in such great numbers, however, the inscriptions are also our best evidence for the existence in theGreek cities of the Roman east of a constant necessity to invest in the prevention of such social conflicts.

(20) Passim: The system of exchange of benefactions for honours could never grind to a halt, on penalty of severe social disorder. What were the potential sources of such disorder? We have discussed in much detail the vastly expanding wealth of the elite and the increasing oligarchisation of socio-political life, together creating huge disparities of wealth and power within the citizenry, as one such source. To a large extent, these tendencies might explain the sheer proliferation of euergetism in the second century ad, when its function of maintaining social cohesion within the citizenry was needed more than ever before.We have also briefly discussed the consequences, for an oligarchic and hierarchically structured society, of a demographic regime of harsh and unpredictable mortality, and the high degree of social mobility it generated. We have seen how the constant upward and downward movement of families through the hierarchy represented a threat to the very continuation of the hierarchy itself, which could best be averted by a constant, ritual re-affirmation of the civic hierarchy, something to which euergetism was ideally suited. The preceding discussion, however, has provided us with yet another potential source of conflict. For the euergetist system did not always ‘work’. Elite benefactors and non-elite citizens might have entirely different opinions as to what types of munificence best served the needs of the citizenry, and in which way citizenship entitlements might best be honoured. The chance survival of a small inscription from Ephesos teaches us that resolving such a conflict might sometimes even involve the intervention of an authority no less than the emperor himself. The text, a letter of Antoninus Pius to the Ephesians dated to ad 145, reads:

(21) Passim: ‘Titus Aelius Hadrianus [Antoninus] Augustus Imperator Caesar, son of the divine Hadrian, grandson of the divine Trajanus Parthicus, greatgrandson of the divine Nerva, pontifex maximus, tribune for the eighth time, imperator for the second, consul for the fourth, father of the fatherland, to the officials of Ephesos, the council and the people. Greetings. / I learned about the generosity that Vedius Antoninus [a wealthy Ephesian notable] shows towards you, but not so much from your letters as from his; for when he wished to secure assistance from me for the adornment of the buildings he had promised you, he informed me of the many large buildings he is adding to the city but that you are rather unappreciative of his efforts. I on my part agreed with every request that he made and was appreciative of the fact that he does not follow the customary pattern of those who discharge their civic responsibility with a view to gaining instant recognition by spending their resources on theatrical shows and distributions and prizes for the games; instead he prefers to show his generosity through ways in which he can anticipate an even grander future for the city . . .’ // Clearly, in ad 145, the Ephesian demos held on to a somewhat different conception of the sort of benefactions that would fit the lifestyle of true citizens than did Vedius Antoninus the wealthy notable. Though, unsurprisingly, the epigraphic evidence is mostly silent on the topic, conflicts of this type may not have been particularly rare. Nor would they always have been particularly innocent. In fact, it may only have been the imperial intervention that caused the Ephesians finally, and belatedly, to acknowledge the generosity of Vedius, five years after the emperor’s original letter was sent. Evidently, the thin layer of homonoia that euergetism spread out over the social and political world of the eastern cities could be very brittle indeed.”

——————————-

(22) Arjan Zuiderhoek, “The politics of munificence in the Roman world- Citizens, elites and benefactors in Asia Minor”, Cambridge University Press 2009;  “Analysing the main categories of benefactions we encounter in a large sample of gifts from Roman AsiaMinor, I argued that, in various ways, they all served the glorification of the Greco-Roman civic ideal.More specifically, benefactions primarily served to underwrite the continued importance of citizenship and the social cohesion of the citizen body by granting all citizens, regardless of wealth or social position, access to those amenities deemed essential to civilised urban life. Thus, elite munificence helped to keep alive the civic ideology which put the unified status group of citizens at the centre of the definition of polis society, in the face of strong countervailing tendencies that led to increasing disparities of wealth and political power within the citizenry. At the same time, euergetism reflected, and helped to propagate, a new hierarchical definition of the civic community. For, even though the citizen community remained of central ideological importance in the imperial Greek cities, the old Classical ideal of the political equality of all citizens made little sense in the oligarchic political environment of the Roman east. Hence the civic community was ideologically reconceptualised as a hierarchy of status groups, headed by the bouleutic elite that effectively governed the city. Such a redefinition was in line with the actual trend in civic society towards increasing hierarchisation (ordo-making), and, particularly in the area of festivals and distributions, benefactors contributed significantly to the propagation of the new ideal by continuously re-emphasising the importance of civic hierarchy.

(23) Passim: It is interesting to note that the hierarchies proposed in various distributions differ slightly in terms of their overall make-up. This leads to the conclusion that in each case a different bargain was struck between benefactor, boule and demos as to the proper definition of the society in which those involved thought they lived. Euergetism’s continuous re-affirmation of social hierarchy served still another purpose, however. The continuous, high rate of social mobility generated by the severe mortality regime of the Roman world presented a constant threat to the establishment of durable social hierarchies. In terms of the ‘personnel’ inhabiting the various ‘sections’ of the social order, society  was in a constant state of flux. And who was to say that newcomers would always stick to the old ways and means? To keep this process of continuous change as changeless (in terms of maintaining the social and political order) as possible, a constant, unceasing re-affirmation of the hierarchical ideal to which society was expected to aspire was therefore a vital necessity. Here was a task that  euergetism, being the preserve of the chief beneficiaries of the hierarchical system, could perform exceptionally well. One element has been conspicuously absent from the analysis of benefactors’ gifts presented in this chapter, and that is the role of the imperial exemplum. This absence is not without its reasons, and I shall give them here. Roman emperors were great public benefactors, as a casual glance at Suetonius’ biographies or the Scriptores Historiae Augustae, or, for that matter, collections of published inscriptions from just about anywhere in the Roman world will confirm. They gave to the population of Rome (Juvenal’s famous panem et circenses), to cities in Italy,  and to cities in the provinces. And certainly, among local benefactors in the provinces, there is bound to have been some emulation of the emperor, or at least local benefactors and emperors often contributed the same sort of things, public buildings and festivals.

(24) Passim: I do not think, however, that the imperial example was one of the main driving forces behind the proliferation of provincial munificence during the late first and second centuries ad. Euergetism as a phenomenon pre-dated the Roman emperors by several centuries: it was essentially an ‘invention’ of late Classical/Hellenistic Greek civic culture. It was practised by both local elites and Hellenistic kings, and, during late Republican times, easily blended in with the Roman traditions of electoral gift-giving and patronage. Euergetism had been very ‘civic’ in character from the outset, focusing, as it did in imperial times, on the citizenry, and consisting primarily of public building, games and festivals, and distributions. It would thus be more accurate to say that, with the onset of the Empire, Roman emperors modelled their behaviour as benefactors very much on the euergetism of Hellenistic elites and, particularly, Hellenistic kings (though of course Rome’s own tradition of electoral public gifts and distributions was also a major influence). If the Roman imperial system had a major influence on the proliferation of public giving, as it surely did, then this was through the internal changes which the incorporation of the eastern cities into the imperial structure brought about in civic society, i.e. the growing oligarchisation of political life, and the increasing accumulation of wealth in the hands of tiny groups of rich families (see Chapter 4).Emperors, in fact, found themselves confronted with the same problem as the provincial oligarchies of rich citizens, only in even more acute form. For how could emperors effectively reconcile the naked truth that they were the absolutist rulers of a military empire with the – legitimating – ideological fiction that they were merely principes, first citizens among a large community of (Roman) citizens?

(25) Passim: To some extent, the Roman division of society in distinct ordines took care of the job: some citizens were simply better than others. Greater virtue, however, had to show from actions to be believable, and hence good emperors, like good notables in the provincial  cities, had to demonstrate their possession of the cardinal virtues of philotimia, philopatria, liberalitas and so forth by public displays of care for 78 SeeGordon (1990). Also, the emperor’s name and/or image appeared on the buildings and during the festivals benefactors donated, and in the honorific inscriptions they received in return, but then the emperor was omnipresent in almost every other aspect of imperial public life (think of the coinage, the dating of documents and so forth). The references to the emperor in munificence simply show that euergetism conformed to the representational standards of Roman imperial public life, that is, it spoke the language of Roman power. This is a fascinating topic, worthy of investigation as such, but it does not, I think, provide a sufficient explanation for the peculiar proliferation of elite public generosity in the eastern provinces during the high Empire. For that, we have to look primarily to the effects incorporation into the Empire had on the internal socio-political dynamics of polis society.

(26) Passom: In this sense, emperors, senators and knights, and local notables, were simply all in the same boat. Hence, they sought similar ideological solutions: besides the reference to the virtues of the ‘good leading citizen’, characteristic of both imperial and local munificence, both emperors and local notables can also be seen to have employed the discourse of the family, with leading citizens being cast in the role of ‘fathers’ of their community,80 and the emperor as the pater patriae, the father of all. Local elites could certainly capitalise to some extent on the fact that they did for their fellow citizens what the emperor did for all, but it was the reality of power, its increasingly unequal distribution within the citizen bodies of the provincial cities, and the social tensions this created, not imitation of imperial example, that primarily drove the proliferation of munificence in the high Empire.”

—————————-

(27) Arjan Zuiderhoek, “The politics of munificence in the Roman world- Citizens, elites and benefactors in Asia Minor”, Cambridge University Press 2009;  “MarcelMauss famously defined gift-exchange as a continuously re-enacted ‘peace contract’ between different social and/or ethnic groups in what he termed ‘archaic’ (i.e. pre-modern, non-western) societies. With its stress on reciprocal exchange as a mechanism for the preservation of social order, Mauss’s model would seem ideally suited to form the point of departure for any account of euergetism, which after all also involves the reciprocal exchange of gifts for honours. There is a drawback, however. The Maussian model, and its various offspring among anthropologists working in the substantivist tradition, was primarily developed to explain the maintenance of social stability in societies lacking formal institutions of government to which a monopoly on the use of violence could be entrusted. The Greek city, however, did have such formal governmental institutions: council, assembly, magistrates, courts and so forth. This fact should truly be central to any analysis of euergetism. Preservation of social stability was indeed a primary function of euergetism, but this preservation took on a very different shape than it did in Mauss’s ‘archaic societies’. It primarily concerned the prevention of conflicts arising within the civic institutional structure.

(28) Passim: That is, euergetism functioned to prevent, ease or overcome potential or actual social conflicts between elite and nonelite citizens resulting from increasing disparities of wealth and political power within the citizenry during the first two centuries ad. Such conflicts found their institutional expression mainly in clashes between boule and demos/assembly, which are quite often attested in the sources from the Roman east. What euergetism did, and that is the central argument of thischapter, was to function as a medium for establishing the legitimacy of the oligarchic socio-political order that had arisen, and continued to develop towards even greater oligarchisation, within an institutional configuration still largely, if remotely, based on the Classical democratic polis. This was one of the ways in which euergetism served to prevent the social conflicts that were bound to arise frequently from such a politically schizophrenic situation. … While political power slowly became the prerogative of a small minority of rich citizens, the members of this elite increasingly felt the need to display their moral superiority by means of various kinds of public contributions. On them rested the burden of proof to show that they truly deserved their elevated position on account of their innate virtuousness. Again, it was deeds that counted. The more privileged the position of the governing elite became, the more individual members had to give evidence of their moral superiority, and they had to do so in hard cash.

(29) Passim: Aristotle, sharp observer that he was, clearly saw the price the rich few had to pay if they wished to hold on to their positions of power:  he magistracies of the highest rank, which ought to be in the hands of the governing body, should have expensive duties attached to them, and then the people will not desire them and will take no offence at the privileges of their rulers when they see that they [i.e. the rulers] pay a heavy fine for their dignity. It is fitting also that the magistrates on entering office should offer magnificent sacrifices or erect some public edifice, and then the people who participate in the entertainment, and see the city decorated with votive offerings and buildings, will not desire an alteration in the government, and the notables will have memorials of their munificence. Here, then, lies the origin of the system of public benefactions we call euergetism. The proliferation of benefactions and honorific inscriptions characteristic of political life in the post-Classical Greek city testifies more clearly than anything else to the pressing need of the members of its elite to acquire ideological legitimacy for their positions of power. The ideological ‘model’ developed in the earlier periods of Greek history as a solution to the problem of social and economic stratification in an egalitarian polis society proved to be eminently flexible. This ‘model’, centred on the notion of the rich man behaving as an …… who showed his philanthropy, generosity and patriotism by using his individual resources for the benefit of the community, in fact became the core notion of the new, more hierarchical, political culture that took shape in the oligarchic post-Classical Greek city.

(30) Passim: It is in essence this ideology of the notable who  owes his powerful position to his virtuous character as exemplified by his benefactions to the community that we encounter in the Greek honorific inscriptions from the Roman imperial period. In this same period, the oligarchisation of political life in the Greek city reached its final stage with what H.W. Pleket has described as the internal oligarchisation of the urban councils. Increasingly, the councils became dominated by small groups of very rich, very influential families, the ….., or primores viri, as Hadrian calls them in a letter to the city of Klazomenai. These families alone among the urban upper classes possessed sufficient resources to make large benefactions frequently. More important in the present context, however, is the fact that their position at the very top of the urban status hierarchy provided them with a strong incentive often to display their moral excellence in the most grandiose fashion possible, and to have recorded, in an equally grandiose fashion, that they did so. As I wrote earlier, they had to show not only that they were good; they had to show that they were very, very good. …”

——————-

(31) Charles Hainchelin, “Les origines de la religion”, Éditions sociales 1955; “Theorieën van Kautsky – Marx, in het manifest van de communistische partij, schreef dat het christendom de decadentie van de antieke maatschappij reflecteerde, een meer precieze aanwijzing, maar hij ging door om de decadentie, deze algemene crisis in de zijn compleetheid te organiseren. In het algemeen, volgens een slecht voorbeeld dat Karl Kautsky heeft gegeven, waarbij hij zich toonde op een abstracte en simplistische manier, die hem limieten opdrukte. / De slaven, werkers die niet tot vrijen werden getransformeerd, en feitelijk als productiemiddelen fungeerden. Doch zij produceerden niet genoeg, het geboortecijfer was zeer laag, het sterftecijfer was zeer hoog, en een economisch system gevestigd op de slavernij kon niet functioneren met alleen natuurlijke vermenigvuldiging. Ook waren er nieuwe oorlogen noodzakelijk om de effectieve bestanden aan arbeidskrachten aan te vullen, om zo de ergastules [werkkazernes] weer aan te vullen. Maar op het moment dat het christendom gaat opkomen, is het zo dat de nieuwe veroveringen aan de grenzen van het imperium, welke nodig zijn om nieuwe razzia’s voor mensen te organiseren, onmogelijk worden; de pax romana, als veelgeprezen, presenteerde zich nu niet als een werkelijkheid, in de tijd die volgde op de decadentie van de antieke slavernij, en nu, in de laatste jaren van de republiek, verhoogde de prijs van de slaven zich, onder het imperium, toonde hen versterkte tewerkstelling zich economisch onvoordelig en in het verloop van de IIIe eeuw – was het moment van de ineenstorting. Aan de andere kant, toonde zich ook geen vergroting van de arbeidsproductiviteit. Het werk van de slaaf werd niet voordelig ten opzichte van de vooruitgang in de techniek, men was vijandig tegenover dit initiatief, een volledige nieuwigheid, en men kende geen andere stimulans dan het geweld.

(32) Passim: Kautsky en zijn epigonen continueerden en bevestigden dat de Romeinse economie zich voorgaande karakteriseerden door het regime van de het grote eigendom, door het bestaan van de latifundia, die de vrije boeren vernietigde; de boeren, verdrongen door de campagnes, gingen naar de steden, zij stonden tegenover de stad, de rangen van het antieke proletariaat versterkend, de klasse welke door de Duitse sociaal-democratie benaderd werd alsof zij gelijk stond aan het moderne proletariaat; deze val van de boeren, die de militaire kracht continueerden, vernietigde ook de hoop op expansieve oorlogen. De maatschappelijke oudheid bewoog zich in een vicieuze cirkel. / Een bepaald tableau van de antieke economie, omvat een gigantische machine die altijd slaven en oorlogen vereist, is aantrekkelijk simpel; het onthoudt talloze juiste trekken, maar het heeft drie essentiële fouten, die haar waarde verminderen. / Vervolgens is er een appel aan het geografisch materialisme, dat meer betwistbaar is; het geografische milieu is, in feite, niet direct verantwoordelijk voor de politieke en ideologische bovenbouw. Haar actie is indirect, bemiddeld, het is fout om op directe wijze te praten over de indirecte invloed op de productie, want zij is variabel met de ontwikkeling van de productiekrachten. Op de tweede plaats schematiseerde Kautsky het exces van een complexe werkelijkheid, die hij analyseerde en die, wij zeggen het, geheel verschillend is van het tableau dat hij gaf; de gentiele maatschappijen die in ontbinding zijn, en bestaan aan de grens van het imperium, enz. / en tenslotte, en dit helemaal, vervangt het de analyse van de interne tegenstellingen door een appel aan de externe antagonismen; het imperium wordt opgerold onder de herhaalde slagen van de barbaren [de Germaanse these van de feodaliteit], maar hoe was het nu met de interne uitholling? En de Romeinse vrede, kon die een andere keus zijn dan de consequentie van deze interne decadentie? Men merkt voorzichtig op dat de financiële moeilijkheden minder kostbaar waren dan de oorlog, die ervoor zorgde dat men ondersteuningen moest betalen aan de Germaanse stamhoofden. Met Kautsky, wordt de oorlog – de externe – en niet de strijd van de klassen de motor van de geschiedenis. /

(33) Passim: Als, in Italië en Sicilië, in de eerste eeuwen, de landbouw domineerde, op de Griekse wijze – en als Griekenland deel uitmaakte van het Romeinse imperium – ontstond er een maatschappelijk karakter dat meer handelsgericht was. Wat meer is, de latifundia, wiens formering de definitieve overwinning van de grote slavenhouders bevestigde, kwamen we niet tegen in ieder deel van het Romeinse rijk, zij domineren allen in Italië, in Sicilië en in Spanje. Zes grote grondbezitters bezitten de helft van Afrika. Nero is er een van. [Plinius, ‘Naturalis Historia’] In deze enorme bezittingen, bestaan alle werknemer bijna helemaal uit slaven, en het slechts effect dat het slavenwerk altijd heeft is zeer bekend, maar het was het zelfde in Syrië, in Egypte, landen waar de landbouwproductie een enorme rol speelde in het leven van het imperium, en waar pachters of semi-pachters bestonden. / Zeker, ging de slavernij voort met de dominerende vorm van exploitatie te zijn, maar het was niet noodzakelijk zo dat we kunnen weten dat het vrije werk volledig verdwenen was. Men vindt ook loonarbeiders op de velden in het zomerseizoen, zeker op het moment van de oogst, het hooien, en de wijnoogst – de stedelijke corporaties gingen hier nog een ongetwijfeld belangrijke rol spelen. / Wij kunnen deze voorbeelden van de vergissingen die door Kautsky nog zijn begaan vermenigvuldigen. / Wij kunnen tegelijkertijd niet vergeten dat de lijnen die Rome, de hoofdstad van het imperium verenigen, ook middellandse zee landen zijn die, volgens de uitdrukking van Marx, zelf dienen als voetstuk. Rome leefde ook afhankelijk van de aristocratie, die zelf ook afhankelijk was van de enclaves en de provincies [doeleinden van de overwinningen, contributies van de oorlog, om daarna methodisch geëxploiteerd te worden]. Het waren alle provincies van Kleinazië en Syrië die leden onder deze exploitatie, de slavenrazzia’s; de massa’s waren hier arm en gedemoraliseerd, net zo god als in Rome en in Italië. Teksten van Latijnse auteurs, onder andere Cicero, tonen de verschillende afdrachten, die later uitgeleefd werden door middel van speculaties ten bate van de geldschieters, de proconsuls, de gouverneurs van de provincies. /

(34) Passim: Wat meer is, in de veroverde landen, vernietigt de invloed van Rome de oude sociale tostanden; de introductie van het Romeinse recht, de gouverneurs van Rome, het grote tribuut verandert ook het leven van de gens, en deze veranderingen, zetten de tendens tot nivellering [en tot aan de slavernij, het enige juridische verschil dat telt in de bevolking, is dat tussen Romeinse burgers, zolang er nog niet veel zijn] voort, welke zich vervolgens reflecteert in de religie, de locale culti verloren beetje voor beetje hen getrouwen, de verborgen ceremoniën telden minder en minder menigten, enz. In al deze domeinen werd er een zekere unificatie plaats, helemaal in de expansie van een ‘universele religie’. Die van het christendom. / Tot aan de Ie eeuw, verkreeg Rome van alle landen die het rijk uitmaakt een enorme kwantiteit aan waarden, maar ondertussen veranderde de situatie, De campagnes van Rome, voorzagen de graanzolders van de stad, maar ook de dienstkleding en het vlees van de troepen. De minder vruchtbare gronden, of de meer uitgeputte, worden verlaten. De eigen defensie schrijft voor dat Rome graan uit Egypte importeert. Rome weet zich onder de industriële en handelsafhankelijkheid van het Oosten, en dat is wat de campagnes verklaart van Crassus, Antonius, Diocletianus, enz. … Een gedeelte van het rijk gaat verder onder het oosterse despotisme van het late imperium. De handel met het buitenland is er ook nog, met China en met India, bijvoorbeeld, en de landen die in dit verband effectief doorgaan met de doorgangshandel – in de eerste plaats Egypte, Palestina, Syrië – kregen vervolgens ook een bijzondere betekenis, helemaal de havens. Egypte dreef handel met het verre oosten door de Nijl en het Rode meer. Deze stad ontving van China de zijde, het kaneel, het porselein; van het verre oosten, de kruiden, de specerijen; uit India, diamanten, parelen, kostbaar hout, goud; uit Arabië: wierook; in Antiochië arriveerden de karavanen uit Iran en Turkestan, welke zelf ook producten verkregen uit China, verschillende soorten hout; deze landen exporteerden de handel die zij verkregen naar Rome, en dat is waarom zich in deze stad, in Italië en in Gallië zich koloniën van oosterse handelaren vestigden, die de oosterse culti met hen meebrachten.”

Man-Vrouw relaties, Oudheid-Algemeen

(1) Div., “Feminism: The Essential Historical Writings”, Vintage – FRiedirch Engels, “The origin of the Family, Private Property, and the State”; “the woman was degraded and reduced to servitude, the became the slave of his lust and a mere insturment for the produciton of childern. This degraded position of the woman, especially conspicuous among the Greeks fof the heroic ad still more of the classical age, has gradually been palliated and glozed over, and sometimes clothed in a mider form; n no sense has it been abolished. / Its essential features are the incororaiton of unfree persons, and paternal power; hence the perfect type of this form of family is the Roman The origianla maning of the world ‘family’ [familia] is not that compound of sentimentality and domestic strife which forms the ideal fothe present-day philistine; among the Romans it did not at First even refer to the married pari and thier children, but only to the slaves. Famulus means domestic slave, and familia is the Total number of slaves belonging to one man … The term was invented ty the Romans to denote a new social organism, whose head ruled over wife and childern and a number of slaves, and was invested under Roman paternal power with rights of life and death oover them alll … Such a form of family shows the transition of the pariring family to mnogamy. In order to make certain of the wife’s feidelity and hterefore of the paternity of th echildren, she is deliverd over unconditionally into the power fothe husband; if he kills her, he is only secercising his rights …

(2) Passim: [The monogamous family] … develops out of the parirng family … its decisive victory is one the signs that civilization is beginning. It si base don the supremacy of the man, the express purpose begint o produce children of undisputed paternity; such paternity is demanded  becaushsche these children are later to tome into thier father’s property ashis natural heirs. It is distinguisheid from paring marriage by the much greater strengt of the marrage tie, which can no longer e dissolved at either partner’s wish. As a rule, it is now only the man who can dissolve it, and put away his wife. Therighti of conjugal infidelyty also remains secured to him, at any rate by custom … We meet this new form of the familie in all its severity among the Greks, while the position ofhtegoddesses in their mythology, as Marx poiints out, brengs before us an earlier period when the position of women was freer and more respected, in the heroic age we find the woman already begin humiliated byt he domination of the man ana by competition from girl slaves. Note how Telemachus in the Odyssey silences his mother.  In Homer Young women are booty and are handed over to the pleasure of the conquerors, the handsomest being picked by the commanders in order of rank; the entire Iliad, it will be remmbered, turns on the quarrel of Achilles and Agamennon over one of these slaves.

(3) Passim: If a hero isof any importance, Homer also mentions the captive girl with whom he shares his tent and his bed. These girls wer also taken back to Greece and borught under the same roof as the wife, as Cassandra was brought by Agamennon in Aechylus; the sons begotten of them received a small share of the parternal inheritance and had the full status of freemen. Teucer, for instance, is a natral son of Telamon by one of these slaves and has the right to se his father’s name. The legitimate wie was expected to ut up with all this, but herself to remian strictly chaste and faithful. In the heroic age a gGreek woman is , indeed more respected than in the preiod of civilizaiton, but to her husband shs is after all nothing tut the mother ofhis legtimate childrena nd heirs, his chief housekeeper and the supervisor of his female slaes, whom he can and does take as concubines if hes o fancies. It is the existence of slavery side by side with monogamy, the presenceof oung, beautiful slave beloning unreservedly to the man, that stamps monogamy from the very beginning wit hits specific charcter of monogamy for the woman only, but not for eth man.  And that is the character it still has today … / Grils [in Athnes] only learned spinning, weving, and sewing, and at most a little reading and writing They lived more or less behind locekd doors and had no company except other women.  The women’s apartments formed a separate part ofthe house, on the uper Floor or at the back where men, especially starngers, could not easily enter, and to which the women retired when men visited the house.

(4) Passim: They never went out without being accompaneid by a female salve; indoors they were kept under regular guard. … In Europiedes a woman is called an oikourema, a thing [the word is neuter] for lookking afther the houde and, aprat from her business of berng chilern, that was al she was for the Athnia – his chief female dosmestic servant. The man had his athletics and his ublic business, from which women were bareed; in addition, hef often had female slaves at his disposal and druing he most flourisheing days fo Athens an etensive systm of protituuin which the state at least favored It was precisely through this sytem of protistution that the only Grek women of personality wer able to develop and to acquire that intelelctual and articstic culutre by which they stand out as high above the general level of clalical womanhoods as th eSpratan women by their qualities of character. But that a woman had to be a hetaira before she coud b woman is the worst condemnation of the Athnian family./ This Athiena family became in time the accepted model for domestic raltions, not only among the Ionians, but to an incerasing extent among all the Greks of themainland and colonies also. But, in spite of locks and gurards, Grek woemen found pelnty of opportunitiy for decieving htier husbands … /

(5) Passim: this is the origin of monogamy as far as we can tracé it back among the most civilized and highly developed people of antiuity. It was notin any way the fruit of indivdual seks-love, with which it had nothing whatever to do; marriages remained as before marrages of convenince. It was the First form of the family to be based, not on natural, but on economic conditions – on the vicotry of private rooperty over primitive, natural communnal property The gReks tehmselves put the mater quite franklyy: the sole exclusise aims of monogamous marriage were to make theman supremen in the family, and to ropagate, as the future hiers to hs welath, children indisputably his own. Otehrwise, marriage was a burden a duty which had to be performred, whehter one liked it or nt, to gods, state and one’s ancestors. IN aathens the law exacted from the man onot ony marriage, but also the performance of a minimm of socallled conugal duties. / Thus when monogamous marriage frst makes its apearance in haistory, it is not as the reconciitation of man and woman, still less as the hghest form of such a reconcilaiton. Quite the contrary. Mongamous marriage comes omn the scene as the subjugation ofthe one seks by the other; it annouces a struggle between the sexes unknown thoughout the hwoele previous prehistoric period. In an old unpublished manusciprt, writen by Marx and myself in 1846, I find the wrods: ‘The fist division of baor is that betwen man and women for the ropagation of chilren.’ And today I can addd: The First class oppositon that appears in history coincides withthe developmento fthe antagonism between man and woman in monogamous marriage, and the frist class oppresion coinciedes what that of the female seks by the male.Monagamous marriage was a great historical step forward; nevertheless, together wth slavery and private wealth, it opens the perid that has lasted until today in which every step forward is also relatively a stap backbward, in which prosperity and development ofr soem is won through the misery and frustration of others. It is the cellular form of cvilied society, in which the nature of the oppostions and contradictions fully active in that society can be alraydy studied. /

(6) Passim: The old compartave fredom of secua intercourse by no menas disapeard wthth vctry of pariring mariage or even of monogamous marriage … co-existedt with monogamous marriage, … sexual interocuuser betwen menand unmarried women outside marriage … as we know, flourished in the most varied forms throughout the howel period of civiliszation and develops more and more into open prostituion … Acutally not merel y tolerated, but gaily practiced, by the ruling classes particuallary it is condemned in wods. But in reality this condemnation fever falls on the men concerned, but only the women; they are despised and outcast, in order that the unconditional supermacy of men over the female seks may be once more rocliamed as a fundamental law of society / But a second contradiction thus develops within monogamous marriage itself. At the side of the husband who embellished his esixtnedce with hetarerism stand the negelcted wife. And one cannot have one side of this contraditon withouthte other, any more than a man has a whole Apple in his hand after eating half.

(7) Passim: But that seem to have been the husbands’ notion, until thier wives taught them better. With monogamous marriage, two constant soical types, unknownhitherto, make thier apearnce on the ciene – the wife’s attendant lover and the cuckold hsband. The husbads had won the vitory over the wives, but the vanqueished magnanimously provided the crown. Togehter with monogamous marriage and hetaeriam, adultyr became an unavoidable social instituion – denounced, severyl pealized, but impossble to supress. At best, the certainty of paternality of the children resten on moral convition as before, and to sovle the insoluble contracdictions the Code Napoleon, Art. 312, decreed: ‘Le’enfant cocu perndant le mariage a pour pére le mari’, the father of a child conceived druing the marriage is – the husband. Such is the final reuslt of three thousand years of monogamous marriage. / Thuis, werever the monogamous family reains true to its historical origin and clearly revelas the antagonm betwen the man and the woman expressen in the maná exclusive supremacy, it exhibits in miniature the same opposiotins and contradicitons as those in which socia has been movig, without power to resolve or overcome them, iver since it split into classes at the beginning of civilizaiton …

(8) Passim: However, monogamous marriage did not by any means appear always and everywhere in the classically harsh from it too among the Greks. Among  the Romans, who, as future world-conquerors, had a larger, if a less fne, viion than the greeks, wo were freer and more respected. A Roman considerd that his power of life and death over his wife sufficiently guaranteed her conjugal fidelity. Here, moreover, the wife equally withthe husband could dissolve the marriage at will.”

Sociologie, Man/Vrouw relaties, Hellenisme

(1) Sue Blundell, “Women in Ancient Greece”, Britisch Museaum Press 1999; “… the Hellenistic age inaugurated by Alexander’s conquestst was a period of large-scae political and social upheaval. Considerable number of Greeks from the mainland migrated to Egypt and Asia wher, togehter withthe descendants ofhte which dominatd the local, working populationsTHey war backed by  al the middle class of Greek soldier-farrmers, who gave military service to the king in return for land. Greek was the official language of the new kingdoms, and many for their cultural institutions were adaptions of ones that had existed in Classical Greece. But the system of government was far from Greek.the Helenctic kings were absolute monarchs, who ruled personally  [wit the help of large Greek bureacracies], and were the souce of all law. Inthe cities which tey fuounded many of the featureof the Grek polis – agora,, councils, magistrates – were reproduced; but het cities were centres for purel local councils, magistrateds – were reproduce; bu tte cities were cenres for a purely local administraitona, and had no political indendence.Only on the Grek mainland, where the control of the Antigonids was in some ares very weak, did the polis regain anything like its former vigorous existnce. / The degree of change expeinece by women in the couse of these transformations would have varid considerably in accordance thteh region ofor class in which they were leving. But in gereal it can be said that there was an erosion ofhte asymmetry beteen the sexes furing the Hellenistic Age, and a consequent improvement in the status of women.

(2) Passim: In the political arena, the most spectacular advance was made by the status of women. In the political arena, the most spectacular advance was made by the women of het Hellenistic Royal families The last Cleopartar was exceptional, in that these rule Egypt directly; but a number of her predessors wielded considerabe influence as the wives or mothers of kings. Outside the Royal circle genuine political competance was an impossiblity for members of both sexes; but thisn itself would have fosterd a willingsness to extend ‘parper privilges to females, and we know of a few instance from cities in Asia and Greece where omen wer awarded honorary citizenship or even magisracies. Of more significance were the rights which women acquired to own and control property. Papyrus documents from Egypt reveal that dring this period women were able to act as sellers and pruchases, as lessons and lessessof land, and as bestowers and receivers of legacies. In some parts of Greece women are recored in insciptions as landowners, as borrowers of money and as slave-owners; and some ofthe females of Sparta are known to have been conspiciously wealthy [see p.156] / Legal and economic rights wer matched, in some ares, by greater personal fredom. Poems such as Theocrus Idyll I,5, which reocunts the conversation of two respcectabel Greek housewives amking thier way through a festival during in the streets of Alexandria, suggest that there had been a relaxation of the physical and ideolocal constrains on women.

(3) Passim:  Male poests were exhibiting a growin interst in women’s private lives; and at the same time a new generation of female poiets, such as Erinna, Nossis and Anyte, was beginning to give voice to woemn’s feelings. Some ofthe new philosophical movements – Epicureanism, Cnicismand neopythagoreanism – included a few women among their adeherent, and, on a more basic level, thre is evidende to whow that in some places grils were being educatd outside the hmoe, in elementary scholls. The gender gap had by no menas been eradicatd, but female and male roles were now wseen as less clearly distinct. This dvelopment is reflectedin Hellnistic art, where the representation of both the male ena dht efemale nude is often handels with overt displays of eroticiam. IN Ptolemainc Egypt the goddess Isiss was begin reshaped as deitiy with wie-ranging functions, and her culets was atrracting nuerous worshsippers of both sexes. / A netwrok of aactors lay behind thse schages. Though in lesser numbers than men, women too were migrating formt he Greek mainland to Egypt and Asia, either with thier husbanksds or as independnet workers. This increadsed mobility would in mnay cases have involved social displacemnet and fiancial hardship, as women moved outside the scope ofhte protection traditionally provided by thier familes BUththe loosening of generational ties, and the rupture of the close relationship between family and polis, would also have led to a weakening of some ofhte social controls over women.

(4) Passim: Perhaps the most potent factor of all was the disbarment of the male citizen from active political involvement. Communal values were disappearing, and wer begin replaced by an ideology of individualim, which produced a focusing of cultural attention on private experiences and emotions, and made the attainmentof personal ahppeiness a legitimate aspiration. The domestic sphere was increasingly recognised as an object of male concern, and as a result het paramentersofthe private and publikc domains became blurred. / The extent to whichthese changes affected the everyday lives of women and men should not be exaggerated. Nor sould the resulting shift in gender relations bes een asan entirely new phenomenonThe gradual privatisationof male interests had been discernnile even in the culture of lat fifth-century Athens and in the fourth cenury it had become more prnounced [above,]. OUtside Athnes, masculine and fiminine spheres may always have been less sharly differentiated, and it is possible hthat isf we possessed adeuate sources for other Classical polies the development s of the Hellenistic Age would appear rather less dramatic.Nevertheless,the scale ofthe olitical transformations occuring in the new era was undeniabllarge, and it is dificult to believe thatthis would not have accelerated the process of change inthe Construction of gender roles.As the very least, this process enables ut to know a little more about ‘what woemn wer doing’ruing the Hellenistic Age. But, sadly, the voices that speak of these doings are still prodomnatly male.”

Overgang slavenhouders naar Feodalisme

(1) D Chresnokov, “Historical materialism”, Progress 1969; “It is significant that the slave revolts, while weakening slave socieity and preparing its downfall, never culminated in a stable victory of the insurgent by achiving the destructiof slavery. Inmost cases the insurgent ere primarily concerne fortheir own liberaltion and not for the dending of slavery as a styem. Furthermore, the slaves who were trying to fre themselves wer often quite willing to become slave-owners themselves. Hence it is not accidentalt hat the slave states of the past usulally perished as the result of militry defeat at the hands of fa  more powerful slave stte which still had a sufficiently large number of peasnts and other ree working peopole to provide the basis fo the military might of this state. / But even in teh victor state the development of slavery led to the labour of fre peasants and artisans being ouste andd, consequetnly, to a weakening of the state’s military power.Enfeebled by the internal struggle fothe slaves and the peasnats artisans who supported them, suh a salve ste easily collapesd at the sightest conflict with ohter stes. Hence  the decisive factor in the downfall of such slave societies was not thier defeat by external forces but internal processes, the incessant struggle of the slaves against the slave-owners.”

—————

(2) Div. “Grundlagen des Marxismus-Leninismus – Lehrbuch“, Dietz 1963; “The time came, however, when the possibilities of progress, which were contained in the mode of production of the slave-holding society, were exhausted and the relations of production became more and more the fetters for the further development of the productive forces. The slave owners, who had cheap slave labor at their disposal, did not seek further improvement of the production facilities. And besides, one could not entrust any complicated and expensive tools to the slave who was interested in his work result. The need for a development of the productive forces demanded more and more urgently the elimination of the relations of production. / This problem could only be resolved through a social revolution. The tribal force of this revolution were those classes and classes who suffered most from the slavery and were therefore directly interested in its elimination, especially the slaves and the poorest part of the free population. The class struggle intensified to the extent that the contradictions matured in the old means of production. It took on the most varied forms – from the deliberate damage to work tools to uprisings in which tens of thousands of people participated. Under the united blows The rising working Kasen and the incursions of neighbouring barbarian tribes, which the slave-holding state, weakened by internal contradictions and internal struggles, could no longer withstand, the slave-holding order finally collapsed and was replaced by a new formation, feudalism. “

sociologie, Man/vrouw relaties, Romeinen

(1) Ovidius / F.A. Wricht, “Ovid – A complete translation of the Ars Amatoria”, George Routledge &Sons ?; “At Rome, from the earliest times, there were three forms of marriage. The First, called confarreatio, was a religious ceremony, in wich the two parties set dwontotgether o none sheep-skin and tasted together a saltedcake made of coarse flour, far. This took place in the presence of at least ten witnesses and only te children of such marraages as these were eligible for certain pirestly offices. Its sanction was Fas, the law of god, and its nearest modern equivalent would be marrageaccoring to the strictest tenets of the Roman Catholic Church.  The second form ws called coëmptio and was a legal ceremony in which the two parties met before a lawyer of magistrat, and thehusband, by a fititious sale, purchased the wife from her father by the procedure per aes et libram. The sanction was Jus, the law of man, and the nearest equivalent would be our marrage at a registrar’office or th French civil marriage before a maire. By either of these two forms the wife passed immediately under her usband’s control – manus – was taken out of her own family, entered that of her husband, and assumed the rights and rank of a daughter therein. They were both of them in fact extensions of het typically Roman institution of patria potest as whereby the elderly male was the absolute master of the whole Household.

(2) Passim: But tere was also a thrid form of marrage, which from the woman’s point of view was much to be prefererd. this was calledusus, and here there was no ceremony, but only conhabitation for a whole year with intention of marriage. Manus was postponed by tis method until the expiration of a year and, more iportant still, provision was made for evading it altogether by the wife absenting herself for three successive nights in the year, and thsdefetting the husband’s prescriptive right tohis ownership of her person. The disadvantage of this form for the wife was that she coud not compel her husband to maintain her, the great and more than compensating advantage was that ther dowry and other property she acquired was her won. Nominally still a member of her father’s family  she was in fact her wownmistress.THeis ‘free mariage’ as it was called is recognized in the Twelve Tables, but in het early period it was probably ess used than the othe two. Women however got their chancewhenth long-drwn struggle fo the Second Punic War had diminished the number of energetic males and after te beginning of the third century marriage by usus became the common form. It was a very great victory for women, and as usual victory was attended with some licence. The behaviour of Roman ladies when the rites of Bacchus were introduced in to italy, and the strnage conspiracy to poison all husbands said to have been discovered abouthte same time, were both things far from commendable, but on the whoe a moderate use was made of suceess and the free marriage produced a race of free women.”

—————–

(3) Div., “A companion to the Roman World”, Blackwell ?; “The discourse of infamia iccludes issues of a very different sort. By simply claimingthat men and women who played in roles that excited thoughts of sex on the part of their audience were morally reprehensible, members of the upper classes evaded their own responsibility as the financial backers of these very entertainments. Like the negative discourse about gladiatorial combat pandering to the base desires of the humble, the authors of this discourse often avoided admitting that they were as fascinated by what was going on in front of them as anyone else. At the same time, there is ample evidence to suggest that a career on the stage was potentially very lucrative for women. Although it falls outside the period covered in this chapter, a rescript of Theodosius in 393 forbidding women of the stage to dress in the clothing that ordinarily could only be afforded by women of the upper classes reflects a much broader social fact (CTh. 15.7.11). Women of the lower classes could make very substantial sums of money from their trade: centuries earlier, Cicero reports that a good female dancer could make 200,000 sesterces for a single appearance, and Volumnia  with whom Mark Antony (and others) had affairs in the forties BCE was able to move in upper-class circles because she had made a great deal of money (Lebek 1996: 44). If the popularity of public spectacle freed some women from dependence upon individual males to advance economically, it also challenged the restrictions placed on women of good family. Women as well as men were the object of the senatus consultum of 19 CE that forbade people of equestrian and senatorial status from appearing on the stage or in the arena. At the same time, of course, it reveals that this was a choice that women could make if they wanted to.

(4) Passim: The range of possibilities in such a career was very great. It extended from wretched careers that might be compared to those of strippers or other workers in modern industries that appeal primarily to male sexual fantasy, to careers that might reasonably be compared to those of modern pop idols in terms of their financial success. At the same time, it also appears that the desire to compete with the past opened up performance opportunities for girls of aristocratic families that were unparalleled in any other period of antiquity. The discourse concerning these careers (which were intended to end with marriage) shows a definite admission that women could participate in some spectacles without damaging their status, and further suggests that in the Greek east (though not in the Latin west) parental support could be found for girls who wanted to perform in a variety of stage and athletic events.”

Sociologie, Hellenisme

(1) Div., “Griechische Geschichte bis 146 v.u. Z”, Verlag der Wissenschaften 1981; “Gaat men alleen van de stedelijke arcitectuur of ook van het beheer uit, dan vind men talrijke parallellen. Zo ver in het Oosten liggende nieuwe stichtingen als Seleukeia uit Tigris of Laodikeya in Syrië laten prcies als iedere andere Griekse oplie een centrale plaats zien voor de mark ten de volksvergadring [agora] een radhuis [buleutérion], een citadel, gymnasium, theater, een tempel voor Griekse goden [die echter met de oriëntaalse geïdentificeerd worden]. Zij hebben een Grieks financiciëel- en belastingsysteem, en voor de wetgeving geld de gangbare relatie tussen de volksvergadeing en de door deze gekozen raadsmannen. Echter vinden zich ook in de oud-Oriëntaalse, dus niet vergriekste steden al deze instellingen, met een uitzoudering. Deze uitzondering is echter belangrijk: het is de verkiesbaarheid en afzetbaarheid van de uitvoerende macht, door welke zich de antieke democratie van de politengemeenschap van de oriëntaalse stad zinvol onderscheid; de basis van de democratie van de klassieke polis met haar formele gelijkheid van de wet [isonomie] waren de autonomie naar buiten en naar binnen in het individuele politeneigendom aan de grond in verbinding met slavenarbeid. Juist in deze fundamentele punten worden in de ‘helleense’polis van de oriënt veranderingen duidelijk, die het begrip van de polis voor deze temporele en geografisch ruime twijfelachtig laten schijnen. De autonomie van de klassie polis, c.q. het bestaan van de polis als zelfsandige staat word vervangen door de door de Helleense koning gewaarborgde ‘vrijheid] [eleutheria]. Was echter de klassieke autonomie een zelfstandigheid uit eigen machtsvolkomenheid van de polis, zo is ook de eleutherie niet verder al seen genadegeschenk van de koning, dat altijd kan worden terug genoemen. De Seleukiden betrachtten de steden, welke zij ‘vrijheid’ gegeven hadden, uitdrukkig ook verder als onderdanen, hoewel in officiële teksten het begrip ‘bondgenoten’ [symmachoi] gebruikt werd. n ieder geval waren de steden ver;icht, militaire ondersteuning te geven alshet nodig was. Zwaarwegend was ook de belasting [phoros of syntaxis], die door de stad aan de koninklijke kas af te dragen was. Weliswaar werd gedeeltelijk ook belastingvrijheid gewwwrborgd, doch uiteindelijk allen om dezelfde redenen als de ‘vrijheid’: wanneer de externe politieke grootmoedigheid oftewel toestond of raadzaam liet schijnen. Ook de indirecte belstingen werden vaak door door de koning opgeëist. Een koninklijke opzicht[epistates], garnizoen en vaak ook koninklijke  rechtbanken waakten over de doorvoering van het van het hof komende bevelen, die soms ook de uiterlijke vorm van brieven hadden, en de meest zichtbare uitrukking van de onderschikking waren. De autonomie bleef geheel op de inner-stedelijke belangen beperkt. Bondgenootschappen en zelfs oorlogen tussen de steden veranderden aan hun feitelijke onvrijheid niets; want verdragen mochten de belangen van de koning niet tegengaan, en locale ruzie’s stoorden de koning alleen dan, wanneer daaronder de inkmsten van de koninklijke kas leden. Samenvattend kan men zeggen, dat nauwelijks een polis in de oriënt een wezenlijke politieke rol te spelen vermocht. /

(2) Passim: Deze situatie ligt in bepaalde bijzonder heden van de stedelijke productieverhoudinge begrond. Aan het begin van de uitriding van de polis-status in de Oriënt zagen zich de steden, bij de toedeling van land uit het koninklijk bezit, geconfronteerd met het het bestaan van dorpsgemeenten op hun land die uit voormalige zogenaamde koninklijke boeren (Gr. Laoi basilikol] gevormd waren. Dezehankeijk, de facto aan hun dorpsgemeenschap en daarmee aan hun grond gebonden boeren, konden noch naar Griekse noch naar Oriëntaalse zienswijze vrije volburgers van de polis worden. Deze toestand had haar oorzaak daarindat de macedonische heersers in hun Oriëntaalse staten, de oud-Oriëntaalse productiewijze in principe onaangetast lieten en een transformative van e economische basis in haar belangrijkste criteria, de eigendoms- en afhankelijkheidsrelaties, nooit gepoogd werden Zoals in vroegere oud-Oriëntaalse staten bleef ook in het hellenistische koningrijk het koningsland de basis van het grondeigendom. Voor de hellenistische koningen berustte deze aanspraak op de voorsteling, dat zij als erfgenamen van Alexander deze ‘door de speer verworven’ c.q. veroverde landen, als eigendom overnamen. Zoals vroegere \oriëntaalse hersers vergafen zij uit dit kongsland wezenlijke delen als eigendom of ter vruchtgebruik aan ambtsdragers, belangrijke pirvate personen of verwanten, aan tempels en soldatenkolonisten [klereuchen], of zij bevestigden ethnische minderheden in het bezit vanhun territorium. Nieuw is alleen maar de uitbreiding van land aan de polis. – De productieverhoudingen worden op de basis van deze eigendoms- en gezitsvormen bepaald door de afhankelijkheid van de producerende beren van eigenaars van hun land. De boeren waren, meestal in het kader van een dorpsgemeenschap, erfelijke grondbezitters, maar ter levering van een meerproduct in de vorm van naturalia, geld of werk voor de betreffende eigenaar verplicht. Daar boven uit had de dorpsgemeenschap ede regeliere hoodelijke belasting aan de kroon aft e voeren. Wiesselde de grond van einaar, dan werden de boeren met het door hun verzorgde land vergeven, verschenkt, verkocht enz. Een wettelijk gevastgestelde binding aan van de boeren aan de grond is weliswaar niet te bewijzen, doch wij kunnen uit een bekende insciptie uit de tijd van Anthiochos I ontnemen, dat zelfs die laoi die hun grond om de een of andere reden hadden verlaten, bij het verkoop van deze grond van de nieuwe eignaar afhankeijk werden: ‘Koning Antiochos groet Metrophanes, Wij hebben aan Laodike [de geschieden vrouw van de koning] Pannukome … en het tot het dorp behorende land … alsmede alle dorpen, die op dit land liggen, en de daar levende boeren [aloi] met al hun bezit … en alle boeren van dit dorp, die bijvoorbeeld nar andere dorpen vertrokken zijn, voor 30 zilvertalenten verkocht’. /

(3) Passim: de zelfde vorm van afhankijkheid overweegt ook op het tempelland, waar de landbouwproducenten eveneens in dorpen samenwonen, maar in familieeconomiën. Zij worden hier vaak katoiken of hierodulen genoemd dochishet onderscheid tot de lanoi met betrekking tot hun rechtelijke status gering.  / Bij de overdraging van koningsland aan een stad word deze als juridische juridische person eigenaar met alle rechten, die op de dorpen van toepassing zijn, die zich op het overgedragen land bevinden. De voorgaande koninklijke laoi worden stedelijke laoi, kunnen zich echter in sommige gevallen als poroiken [‘omwonnenden’] laten inschrijven, waardoor zij een soort van bergers zonder politike rechten en tenminste de facto eigenaar van hun grond werden. Als bekend kan gelden dat land van de voormalige koninklijke boeren ook door de stad kon worden gegeven aan de politen, als individueel eigendom. IN dit geval werde de laoi afhankelijken van private individuele personen, zo dat ich op typisch ‘antiek’eigendom typisch ‘oriëntaalse’ afhankelijkheidsvormen vonden. Hoewl dergelijke gevallen uitzondering bleven, is het duidelijk, dat  bij een zo heterogene  structuur van de eigendoms- en afhankelijkheidsrelaties zowel de positive van de oud-oriëntaalse gemeente verzwakte als ook het eigenijke systeem van de polis uitgehold werd. De polis in de orient was dus van het begin af niet allen van haar autonomie beroofd, doch zij was aan de basis ook aan een oppermachtige oriëntaale invloed bloottesteld. / Daar ook in de tot poleis verklaarde steden de oriëntaalse bevolking getalsmatig verreweg in de meerderheid was – ondanks dat ze vaak in aparte wijken woonden – bleef het \ Griekse karakter’ daarmee op de voorgaand genoemde uiterlijkheden beperkt. Dat betekende echter, dat niet slechts het wijde land buitn de steden door de hellenisering onberoerd bleef, doch dat zelfs in economisch leidende steden geen diegaande veranderingen in de basis van de oud-oriëntale maatschappelijke ordening volgden. / De zelfde vraag blijft nog aan de kwaliteit van de slavernij in de ‘hellenistische’ Oriënt te onderzoeken. Natuurlijk gaat het hier slechts om het aandell van de salvenarbied in de productie. Het reeds vroeg in de Oriënt bekende eigenom aan mensen was geen eigendom aan productiemiddelen, doch aan levende ‘bjecten’, die diensten verrichtten: oppassen op het huis, het uitvoeren van zakelijke kwesties, bevrediging van persoonlijke behoeften van de heer o.a. De typeische antieke productieslavernij was [ondanks de economische basis ook van de antieke maatschappij] daarengen aan de stad e naan de markt gebonden. Beide bleven echter in de oud-riëntaalse maatschapij overwegend centra van de hofhouding en de langeafstandshandel. /

(4) Passim: de verbreiding van poleis was in de Oriëntaalse gebieden zeer gedifferenciëerd. Voor Egypte gold eigenlijk, dat slechts Alexandreia plis, al het overrige land tot het de Nijl-katarakten koningsland [chora] was. Daarmee gold voor de Egyptenaar hetzelfsde als voor de inheemse bevolkingen in de Oriënt :uberhaput.: zij waren geen politen, hadden daarmee geen staatburgerlijke rechten. Voor deregeling van het samenleven in de dorpen en andere administratieve eenheden waren era parte Egyptische rechtsnormen. Slechts de minder belangrijke steden Jaukratis en Ptolemais alsmede de Kyrenische Pentapolis bezaten eveneens de polisstatus,. / Van de zogenaamde 76 stedelijke stichtingen van Seleukos en zijn opvloger hebben slechts de hoofdstad Antiochia met haar haven Seleukeia Pieria en het militaire centrum Apameia in Syrië alsmede het nandelsknooppunt Seleukeia aan de Tigris international betekenis verkregen. Europos [Dura], Palmyra [Tadmor], Seleukeia [Ausa] en andere steden van het Seleukidenrijk waren oude Oriëntaalse nederzettingen, die slechts een Grieks vernis gekregen hadden / Met de Hellenistische stedelijke stichtingen baande zich tendensen tot de antieke markteconomie in het Nabije Oosten aan. IN de nieuwe steden ontstoden Ergasterien alsmde werfen in de nieuwe havens. Zo kennen wij Dokken in Laodikeya en Seleukeia in Syriëj, koninklijke ergasteriën in Pergamon enx. Gevat werden door deze tendens da nook oude Oriëntaalse steden en hun ambachten, zoals de purperverveijen in Tyros, de glassmelterijken in Sidon, de linnenweverijen in in Tarsos, de ververijen in Sagalassos [Pisidië] e.a. Toch is het moeilijk, uit de literaire- en inscriptie-bronnen op de status van de arbeiers te sluiten. De weinig zekere aangaven, die wij over de producenten in de ergasteriën van \pergamon, Antiochia, Teos, en Sagalassos hebben, duiden meer of minder op vast aan de ambachtelijke arbeidsplaats gebonden, in Egypte overwegend zelfs ‘gekaerneerde’ vrije loonarbeiders. Natuurlijk is het wat twijfelachtig, tenppzichte van de bewegingsbeperking – de arbeiders mochten hun arbeidsplek niet naar eigen goeddunken veranderen -, überhaput van ‘vrije’ producenten te spreken; doch zij onderscheiden zich van slaven op een beslissend punt, dat zij zelf hun arbeidskracht verkochten, terwijl die van de slaven in een koopverdrag tussen oude en nieuwe slavenhouders met hun persoon gekocht werd. Als slaven zijn bijvoorbeeld de dokarbeiders in de Fenicische steden bekend. /

(5) Passim: In de mijnbouw werkten meestal mensen die die wegens een of andere overtreding tot dit werk veroordeeld waren. Hun status was gelijk aan die van slavenechter snelden zij niet het antieke type voor data ls waar volledig mobile en zelf arbeidsmiddel was. / Ook op landbouwgoderen zijn slave naan te treffen, doch zij staan eerder in dienst van het huishouden dan van de productie. In documenten over eigendomsoverdragingen van land worden de weinige slaven met naam genoemd, terwijl de afhankelijke boeren en bloc geoemd worden. Samenvattend moet vastgesteld worden dat zich de antieke vorm van de slavernij weliswaar in enige stdeelijke cnetra van de Oriënt zeker vind, maar op geen enkele manier voldoende, om een antieke periode van de economische maatschappepelijke formative daaruit te funderen. / Als heersen devorm van eigendom is voor het grondeigendom van een gepriviligeerde, met het hof in verbinding staande laag en dat van een ‘grieks-Macedonisch minderheid aan de stedelijke productiemiddelen te zien, De kwalitatieve en kwantitatieve rangorde van de van deze eigendomsvormen afhankelijke producenten in de hellenistische orient laat het volgende zien: in het zuivere bezit van grond zijnde boeren met onderscheidenis afhankelijkheid van de eigenaars – mer of minder aan een koninklijk of door de koning vergeven bedrijfgebonden handwerkers – mobiele, van productiemiddelen helemaal vrije slaven en dagoloners, overwegend in Ergasterië actief. De totaalstructuur van de ‘hellenistische’ maatschappij buiten het Egyptische gebied is dus blijkbaar oud-Oriëntaals, gemodificeerd door een antieke invloed, die ertoe nood, wannner niet zelfs dwigt, van een bijzondere fase in de ontwikkeling van de oud-Oriëntale klassenmatschapij te spreken. Deze maatschapelijke eigendoms- en afhankelijkheidsvormen hebben later een grote invloed op de vorming van sociale vormen in het Romeinse rijk uitgeoefend en de overgang tot het feodalisme mede-beïnvloed.”

——————

(6) Everett Ferguson, “Backgrounds of Early Christianity”, Willima B. Eerdmans publishing company 1993; “Texts containing the ‘constitution and by-laws’ of certain Egyptian associations of Hellenistic and Roman times reveal some organizational differences between Egyptian and Greco-Roman associations. A Greek or Roman association was commonly formed with the idea that it was to last indefinitely, but these Egyptian statutes are limited to one year’s duration, although they were capable of renewal.The idea of a corporate body was not dveloped n Egypt, and associations posssessed no rights or duties beyound those of individueal members. The meeting place was a public temple, not a private shrine or other building belonging to the associaiton of a member as would have been common in Greece. The only officials were a president and his assistant, both of whom were empowerd to enforce the regulations of the society. The laws of het society were of the nature of a contract to which them embers bound themslelves. In this last feature and in many of the other provisions the Egyptian clubs were like their Greek counterparts: due and contributions for special occasions monthly banquet, assistance fto fellow members, assuming burial responsibilities, and fines for violating the rules of conduct.”

———————-

(7) William Tarn & GT. Griffith, “Hellenistic civilisation”, Methuen 1959; “With the weakening of the city there came an enormous growth of non-political private associations and clubs. There had been a few such clubs in fourth-century Athens [the fifth-century oligarchic clubs were another matter], but Demetrius of Phalerum [317-307] had forbidden the formation of new ones; and the great outburst of associations all over the Greek world dates from 300 onwards. Most were very small; that from the Dionysic artists, a membership of 100 was quite unusual. They were primarily social and religious bodies grouped round the worship of some god; possibly the thiasoi were more purely religious, which the eranoi, where the subscriptions were of importance – one had an entrance of 30 drachmae – were primarily social bodies. About 200, family associations aspire, founded by some individual to perpetuate the family memory, the priesthood being hereditary among his descendants. Every club had its temple, however tiny but finance was a perpetual difficulty; many let their temples for secular purposes when not in use, like the Egretes club at Athens, who in leasing theirs reserved one day a year for their annual festival. Epictetus’s club at Thera, one of the wealthiest, had an annual revenue for its founder of 210 dr, and one at Athens once ended a year with 1770 dr. in hand; but these were exceptions, and the clubs came more and more to depend on some wealthy member who would bear expense and was honoured with statue, or which he paid himself – exactly what was happening in the cities. /

(9) Passim: These clubs were in no sense friendly Societies; they might help a member in trouble, or see to his funeral, probably an excuse for a diner; but their it ended. Associations of men named from their trades began to appear at Athens and Cos, but the professions trade guild was practically unknown to Hellenism, unless in Egypt; true trade guilds only evolved under the Roman Empire, and finally Justinian’s Code took account of their rules, as did English common law of the custom of merchants. Usually a club had no political meaning; but in the lst struggle of the Achaean League against Rome clues of ‘Patriots’ appeared, i.e. men united to uphold the constitution of their fathers. The club modelled itself on the city organisation; it had official with similar names and passed resolutions like city decrees; and it became so much the standard model that the most divers forms of activity –the philosophic schools, the museum at Alexandria, the Dionysian artists, Ptolemy’s garrison troops, the poets domiciled at Athens, the physician trained t Cos or elsewhere, the Old boys from this of that gymnasium – adopted the same form of organisation the number of clubs was great; in 146 the small city of Trouzen possessed 23; obviously they met a want, and prevented the individual feeling lost in vast new world. That their life seems to us tiresome and unutterably boring is sure, but is hardly worth saying; there is no evidence either that The Greek was bored with his life or that the men of 2.000 years hence would not be equally bored with ours. The club’s most important function in Greek life was to form the natural avenue for foreigners and foreign worships entering a city; purely Greek clubs occur at Athens and Rhodes, but normally they were either foreign or mixed, the latter assisting to break down racial barriers: thus one at Cnidus, besides Greeks, continued a Thracian, a Phoenician, a Pisidian, a Phrygian, and a Libyan slaves were sometimes members, but seemingly the first known slave club occurs only late in the period,  in Egypt.

Sociologie, Germanen

(1) Aaron J. Gurjewitsch, “Das Weltbild des mittelalterlichen Menschen”, C.H. Beck 1980; “In het Germaanse recht is de hoogte van het weergeld in de regel uitgedrukt in een bepaalde geldsom; deze som moest men, naar de voorschriften van het ‘recht’ om te oordelen, iedere keer betalen wanneer een analoge misdaad met een mens gebeurde – die tot de betreffende maatschappelijke categorie behoorde [adel, vrij, minder vrij]. Er bestaat echter reden om aan te nemen dat de hoogte van het weergeld in werkelijkheid nooit slecht op grond van de in de wetboeken gefixeerde schalen vastgezet werd. In ieder concreet geval werd een bepaalde waardering gedaan die de hoogte van het weergeld bepaalde. De principes, door welke de boeken zich lieten leiden, blijven onduidelijk. Het is aan te nemen dat het bedrag van de vergoeding in niet geringe mate door de wisselwerking der krachten en de maatschappelijke invloed der naar verzoening strevende geslachten afhing. De misdeelden streefden namelijk naar maximale compensatie. Doch in een reeks van gevallen stonden de personen die weergeld moesten betalen er op een hogere vergoeding te betalen. Deze op het eerste gezicht eigenaardige omstandigheid verklaart zich blijkbaar uit de bijzondere natuur van het weergeld en daaruit wat de mensen van hun tijd daaronder verstonden. De hoogte van het weergeld was een kenteken van de maatschappelijke toestand zowel van diegene die het kregen, als van van de betalenden – en daarom liet zich de hoogte van het weergeld een het sociale prestige van de individuen, families en geslachten zien. Dus stelde het weergeld niet slechts een vaak behoorlijk grote som voor, die men vaak als materiele compensatie voor de veroorzaakte schade dringend zocht. /

(2) Passim: Hoewel in de ‘volksrechten’ de hoogte van het weergeld en alle andere betalingen in geld uitgedrukt is, werden deze in werkelijkheid in belangrijke mate met eigendom betaal, daar niet zo veel geld in omloop was. Maar niet ieder vorm van eigendom werd ter betaling van weergeld aangenomen. Men nam graag vee aan. In een reeks van wetboeken is vastgelegd welk aantal van dieren [gewoonlijk koeien] men i.p.v. geld ter betaling an weergeld moest afgeven. Hiernaast kon men slaven, wapens, malievesten, land – en doeken afgeven. Ales, wat als compensatie gebruikt werd, moest van hoge kwaliteit en zonder gebreken zijn. Doch men treft ook andere inperkingen aan. Zo mocht bij de Noren als betaling van weergeld slechts erfelijk land afgegeven worden dat zich in het verloop van een reeks van generaties in het bezit van de familie’s bevond en praktisch onverkoopbaar bezit was. Verworven, ingekocht land – op welk de beperkingen van het erfland niet van toepassing waren – mocht men niet als weergeld afgeven. Blijkbaar laat zich hier een bijzondere verbinding tussen de familie en het weergeld zien. De compensatie, die men voor de gedode verwanten kreeg, veranderde zich niet in een object van onteigening – en het daartoe behorende land alsmede de onroerende goederen bleven in het voortdurende bezit van de familie. /

(3) Passim: Het weergeld was een teken van de verzoening van familie’s die in vete’s lagen. Gelijktijdig diende het als zichtbaar teken van de sociale toestand van de persoon voor wie betaald werd en zijn geslacht. Daar de geldsom of de andere rijkdommen, die in het moment van het vergelijk tussen de moordenaars en de verwanten van de moordenaars betaald werden, een zo belangrijke symbolische functie uitoefenden, onderlag het verkregen weergeld nauwelijks aan gebruik en werd ook niet vrij uitgegeven. Soms achterlieten mensen, wanneer ze stierven, naast andere dingen ook hun weergeld aan de kerk. In dit geval echter is niets bekend van moord of een soortgelijke misdaad die door weergeld werd verzoend. Daar in het testament de som die tegemoet komt aan het weergeld tamelijk veel aandacht krijgt, kan men aannemen dat deze betaling een bijzondere betekenis toegemeten krijgt; zij was op een bijzondere manier met de mens verbonden en drukte zijn maatschappelijke status uit. De landbezitters die de kloosters schenkingen in de vorm van land maakten, kochten het soms – nadat er enige tijd verstreken was – terug, nadat zij hun weergeld betaalden. Hier is de verbinding van betaling, die het leven van het individu beschermde, met zijn erfelijk bezit, duidelijk te herkennen.”

—————–